Product life cycle of international trade and investment
New international division of labor
Fordism and post-fordism
Multinational corporations (MNCs) are powerful tools of economic development, because they can reap benefits from some of competitive advantages of different countries (think of the factors identified in an earlier lecture), even while using these advantages to earn economic rents for their corporate assets (we discussed corporate assets in an earlier lecture). We'll use these powerful capabilities of MNCs to help us understand three developments in world economic development: the international product life cycle, the "new international division of labor," and the breakdown of the fordist system of wealth generation.
PRODUCT LIFE CYCLE OF
INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT
• Raymond Vernon, 1966, "International trade and investment in the
product life cycle"
• Concerned with only certain industries:
With these assumptions, Vernon built a story of these particular
kinds of products facing
1) introduction in the highest-income, highest-wage country
where the products found their first demand; production is small-scale,
changing, expensive, and uses highly skilled L; demand is not very
price-elastic, because of differentiation, and the nature of pioneering
adopters
2) growth of demand and production in the original country,
with declining costs and prices; some export demand from countries
with lower incomes and wages — the high-wage, L-scarce country is exporting
L-intensive products
3) maturity of demand in the original country, with standardized
and increasingly K-intensive production; establishment of foreign
operations in newer markets to serve them and to overcome real or threatened
trade barriers
4) decline of product demand in the original country, with increasing
competition from other suppliers and other products; the cost pressure
and the ability to embody the technology in (a) capital equipment and (b)
standard operating procedures pushes production "offshore" to low-wage
countries, using financial capital and capital equipment from the originating
country — the high-wage, labor-scarce country (e.g., the U.S.) is importing
capital-intensive products, because the capital and
technology are mobile within the multinational corporation (MNC),
while the less-expensive L is not mobile.
This dynamic model of production technology explains, for a limited class of goods, US exports of these goods while they are labor-intensive (skilled-labor intensive) and import of these same goods later, when they are capital-intensive (with the capital coming from global capital markets, not necessarily from the countries where production occurs).
However, this model differs from the factor-proportions (Heckscher-Ohlin) theory:
NEW INTERNATIONAL DIVISION OF
LABOR
Think about our simplistic, cost-minimizing model of industrial location
(see notes
from that lecture). We noted that as the costs of transportation
have declined, interregional (and international) differences in labor costs,
tax rates, and agglomeration economies became more important influences
on industrial location.
Some researchers have used this increased influence of immobile factors to define a "new international division of labor" (NIDL), in which some low-wage regions of the world use imported technologies to produce moderately labor-intensive products for high-income regions. While the traditional international division of labor (based on immobile labor, capital, and technology) entailed manufactured exports from wealthy countries and raw-material exports from poorer countries, the NIDL (based on mobile capital and technology and immobile labor) entails
A parable of mass production
Henry Ford recognized that he could dramatically reduce the cost of
the Model T if he could produce and sell more of one model than any other
automobile maker had ever considered selling.
Fordism
This mutually reinforcing system
of big business, big government, and big labor has been called "Fordism."
Basically, it entails standardized mass production at wages that allow
the mass consumption that supports the scale that mass production requires.
In addition, institutions such as government macroeconomic policy, military
policy, and fiscal policy, and labor unions, support the expansion of markets
and the reduction of costs (except labor costs).
The international product life cycle and the NIDL can endanger Fordism,
to the extent that some mass production occurs in places that are not markets
for mass consumption. Instead, the mass production in LDCs (using
technology and capital from industrial countries) was aimed at export to
U.S. markets. The closed system of mass production and mass consumption
became less closed.
The real wages of U.S. industrial workers stagnated, and U.S. consumption
becomes more varied: a large and growing market for expensive goods
and services; a large and growing market for lower-price goods and
services. In addition, some of the LDCs become substantial mass-consumption
markets, for even lower-price goods and services.
Post-Fordism
Since the 1970s, communication and production technologies have allowed
worldwide production and worldwide competition (in some sectors of the
economy). Industrial competition has increased, and competition has
become based not only on cost (which mass production steadily reduced),
but also on rapidly changing, specialized products for business, government,
and consumers. Successful manufacturers are learning to produce in
smaller, more specialized batches, using flexible equipment and contracted
(rather than long-term) workers.
This combination of
The geographic bases of post-Fordism are: