First question: What's an economy for?
In 1776, Adam Smith wrote that The Wealth of Nations depends
upon the goods and services available to their citizens. Under this
view of political economy (generally referred to as a liberal economic
view -- which has little to do with current-day labels of liberal and conservative),
governments should organize themselves and their economic management to
maximize the aggregate level of goods and services that their citizens
can consume (now and in the future).
(This differs from alternative interpretations of how and why a government should manage a national economy, such as increasing the self-sufficiency of the country, or increasing the government's store of wealth, or maintaining a moderately even distribution of wealth among its citizens).
Second question: How can we maximize this wealth?
We can maximize this wealth -- the goods and services available
to the citizens of a country -- by
Third question: What determines which activities
are the most productive ones for a given country?
The particular mix of resources available in a country determine which
products will be most efficiently produced there. (Note: we're
assuming that different products require different proportions of resources,
and that different places have different proportions of resources).
Fourth question: What determines whether a given
country should engage in trade?
If the opportunity costs for producing the same items are different
among countries, then each country should specialize in the production
for which its opportunity cost is lower than for other production.
Summary of basic trade theory (this
is another one of the very, very important things to take from this course):
The basic principle of most modern trade theories
is that the global system benefits from each region or country using its
resources to produce what it can produce most effectively and efficiently
-- with lower opportunity costs than it faces to produce anything
else -- and exchanging some of this output for goods and services that
other regions use their resources to produce.
As a result, the resources of every region are
being used most productively.
Note that the possibility of system-wide gains from trade persists, even when a given country has an absolute advantage in the production of no product.
Specialization and trade should occur according to the relative opportunity costs of production in each country, measured in terms of the alternative production given up to produce a tradable good. This is the principle of comparative advantage (see note 1).
Example:
Tea | Wheat | |
Sri Lanka | 10 | 10 |
United States | 5 | 4 |
Fifth question: What explains the differences in opportunity costs for producing the same product in different countries?
If we assume:
How can we measure "abundant" and "scarce"? Imagine the ratio of (a) the price that a nation's labor market will pay for an additional unit of labor to (b) the price that that same nation's capital market will pay for an additional unit of capital. Compare that ratio in two countries. The country where the ratio is higher is labor-scarce and capital-abundant, compared to the other country.
Sixth question: What are the (theoretical) results of specialization and trade according to comparative advantage?
The basic result is that production should occur where the factors intensively used in that production are abundant. Thus, abundant factors around the world are paid more than if there were no trade. Most importantly, resources (factors) are being used to produce what they can produce at lowest opportunity cost: world output can be higher than without trade.
Note that with national (or regional) specialization and trade according to comparative advantage, the demand for, and price paid to, a nation's (or region's) abundant factor(s) is increased -- and, as a result, producers may substitute other factors. This is clearly related to our study of spatial interaction, in which we noted that if one region has an abundance of some factor relative to other regions (e.g., asparagus in Central Washington), establishing interaction with other regions (e.g., metropolitan Seattle) will increase the price of the abundant factor in its origin region -- because there's now more effective demand for the factor. What are the abundant factors in the US? As the US trades more with the rest of the world, what US factors should find their prices increasing? What possibilities are there for substitution away from these factors?
Analogously, the price paid to a nation's (or region's) scarce
factor(s) is reduced, because some of the products that intensively
use those factors will be imported. Producers in that nation may
begin to use a higher proportion of the scarce factor than before
trade. What are the scarce factors in the US? As the US trades
more with the rest of the world, what US factors should find their prices
falling? What possibilities are there for substitution toward these
factors?
COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE
A country's competitive advantage might be defined as those
sectors
in which companies based in a given country have profitable worldwide markets.
The
theory of factor proportions can be made more complex, to reflect the complex
ways in which companies develop competitive advantages based on their home
countries. Economist and business scholar Michael Porter has done
this through a long, empirical investigation (see note
3), and came up with a "diamond" of four
national characteristics that seem to influence the sectors in which companies
based in those countries have worldwide competitive advantages.
1) availability and quality of factors
(labor by type, infrastructure, resources)
- basic (inherited) versus advanced (created)
- generalized (infrastructural) versus specialized (industry)
- role of [selective] factor disadvantages? (esp. when
they presage worldwide situations)
2) size and nature of demand
- both size and rate of growth, to encourage investment
- sophisticated or demanding domestic markets may push companies
to improve the quality of products, which will make them even more competitive
internationally (see note 4)
3) presence and quality of supplier and supporting (including service) industries
4) nature and rules of competition
Quality factors, pace-setting demand, good supplier networks, and sufficient
competition to keep firms' attention are all
obvious ways in which the national [or local] environment can assist
the development of competitive advantage. However,
competitive advantage can be found in less obvious ways, as in an unusual
factor or sales market that leads a firm to
specialize in particular product attributes that leads to a specialized
advantage worldwide.
Note, however, that improved competitiveness on the part of industries
in any trading country -- not just "our" country -- will increase global
productivity, the rate of technological advance, and the productivity with
which global resources are used.