University of Washington
Geography 349
Trade, Resources, and the Natural Environment


How and why might increased international trade affect the natural environment?

1)   Positive impacts may come from the ways that the environment affects costs that are internalized by firms:

a)    International procurement of resources where they are most available.

b)    Production/refining so as to minimize overall transportation costs.

 

2)   Negative impacts result from economic externalities – actors don’t bear the costs of their actions – and non-economic considerations

a)    Externalities:

i)      Under current factor pricing, the price of fossil fuels doesn’t reflect the externalities from their consumption.  To the extent that trade increases output, and that output requires fossil fuels, this is an indirect cost of trade.

ii)    Air pollution and CO2 emissions from international transportation:  shippers pay for the fuel, but don’t pay for pollution and other emissions (unless that were somehow accounted for and added via a tax to the cost of fuel).

iii) Differential environmental standards across countries mean that some countries can stay “green” by importing “brown.”

b)    Non-economic considerations:

i)      Resource depletion – though see how Atkinson & Hamilton attempt to provide a way to introduce depletion into an economic analysis.

ii)    National security implications of environmental change and resource depletion.




Notes on the optional readings

Atkinson, G. and Hamilton, K.  2002.  International trade and the ‘ecological balance of payments.’  Resources Policy 28: 27-37.

This article provides a working definition of sustainable development:
  • "a development path is sustainable if welfare per capita does not decline along the path" [27-28].
  • "in order to achieve sustainability, a country that is liquidating its natural assets must set aside sufficient economic resources to finance investment in other forms of wealth (so that substitutions of, for example, natural and produced assets are possible)" [28].

However, a country can use resource-intensive imports to substitute for depletion of domestic resources.  It's important to account for the resource-intensity of imports before calculating the investment a country should be undertaking to remain sustainable (as defined above).  The framework for the ecological balance of payments "allows us to calculate the derived [i.e., indirect] demand for resources in the country of final use” [p.27].  The authors undertook an empirical analysis of the direct and indirect resource importation by EU, Japan, and US in 1980, 1985, and 1990.  

Here, let me explain their input-output accounting framework.

At the beginning of the quarter I noted that a common way to subdivide GDP is:
GDP = C + I + G + X – M.  
Y, or national income, is the same as GDP.  Atkinson & Hamilton ignore G (I presume they include government expenditures within “consumption”), and modify the equation for a 2-country world:
Y1 = C1 + I1  + X12 - X21  and
Y2 = C2 + I2  + X21 - X12 ,
where X12 is the flow of exports from Country 1 to Country 2 and X21 is the flow in the other direction.

They create a trade coefficient q that is simply qij = Xij / Yj (the ratio of a country’s exports to its total GDP),
so that Xij = qij Yj (think of q as the export intensity of the country’s economy) and thus
Y1 = C1 + I1  + q12 Y1q21 Y2
(in case algebra gives you a headache, this equation says that a country's total income equals its consumption, plus its investment, plus its export intensity times its income, minus its import intensity times its income.)

and then they solve for both countries simultaneously using matrix algebra.

They then define a “resource depletion vector” which is basically the value of domestic resources used in a country per year, divided by the country’s annual GDP, and, because they know the resource depletion vector for each country and they know each country’s imports, they can define a global resource consumption vector that estimates the value of domestic and foreign resources used to satisfy a country’s C + I + X – M in a given year.

The difference between those two resource depletion estimates (how many resources the country depletes to produce its exports, minus how many resources the country's imports deplete) is the country’s net importing of global resources, or its “ecological balance of payments.”



Peters, G.P.  and Hertwich, E.G.  2006.  Pollution embodied in trade: the Norwegian case.  Global Environmental Change 16: 379-387.

The authors developed a method for estimating the “pollution” (specifically, CO2) emissions in the imports, exports, and domestically oriented production of countries, recognizing that the emissions per unit of production varies by country.  

The article explains why consumption-based estimates of a country's pollution may be a better basis for environmental negotiation than estimates based on the location of production.

Don't worry about the technical side of the paper (Section 2);  read it sufficiently to have an idea of what the authors are trying to do, with what sorts of data.



Liu, H., Xi, Y. Guo, J., and Li, X.  2010.  Energy embodied in the international trade of China: an energy input-output analysis.  Energy Policy 38: 3957-3964.

“In this paper, we evaluate the energy embodied in goods produced in China during 1992-2005…”
  • Note that input-output (I-O) analysis recognizes the precise material and service inputs required per unit of each type (industry) of output.  This allows you to tell the direct requirements of each input for a unit of output, and also to tell how much of each material or service is indirectly required – because each direct input is produced by requiring its own specific mix of inputs.
  • The estimate how much energy is used in production of each sort of output, by adding “energy” sectors to the I-O matrix, and solving for the direct and indirect use of energy in the “export” output sector.
“…and use input-output structural decomposition analysis to identify five key factors causing the changes of energy embodied in exports:
  1. direct primary energy efficiency (how much energy per unit of production)
  2. primary energy consumption structure (how efficiently the energy is generated)
  3. structure of intermediate inputs (how many inputs of what energy intensity)
  4. structure of exports (how energy intensive is the particular mix of exported products)
  5. scale of exports (how much is exported)


What are the implications of all this?

1.     The increased production and transportation that accompany specialization and trade comes at the cost of increased use of energy and increased environmental pollution.

2.     Because different types of products have different energy and emission requirements, the country-specific impact of increased output varies by the kinds of products in which a country specializes.

3.     The country-specific impact of increased output also depends on the energy sources on which the country relies.

4.     The country-specific impact of increased output also depends on the technology used – which will vary according to (a) overall level of technology;  (b) factor-price ratios;  and (c) environmental regulation.

5.     It probably makes sense to be as concerned with the environmental consequences of a country’s consumption – whether satisfied through domestic production or through imports – as we have been about the environmental consequences of a country’s production.







copyright James W. Harrington, Jr.
revised 20 May 2012