University of Washington
Geography 207
Professor Harrington
Location of Urban Activities Under Land-Use Competition
Contents:
The urban rent gradient
Complications and transititions
Political realities

THE  URBAN  RENT  GRADIENT
Recall our equation of the maximum rent that will be offered for a piece of agricultural land, a function of the intensity of a potential land use, the profitability of that land use, the expense of transporting the products of the land use to market, and the distance of the particular piece of land from the market center:

LR = Q (p - c) - Qfk

where
LR = maximum rent that a particular agricultural use can pay at a particular point, in dollars/acre
Q = output (a measure of intensity of use), in tons/acre
p = market price (a measure of value of the crop), in dollars/ton
c = production cost, in dollars/ton
f = transport cost, in dollars/ton-mile
k = distance from the market center to the point in question, in miles.

Recall that this equation yields a landscape of concentric circles of different agricultural land uses, centered on the market, because different land uses have different outputs per acre and different transport costs.

Well, we can use this same logic to conceptualize the pattern of urban land uses.  At the urban scale, even small users of land matter:  houses, factories, train stations, and office buildings that appear as “dots” in the market center of an agricultural tableau are noticeable users of land at the urban scale.

Each land use has a “profitability” (r - c) — the amount of revenue generated per square foot minus the costs of generating that revenue:

Each land use can be conducted at different densities (D):  the number of rentable square feet per acre. Each land use has goods and people to be transported among the various functions:
While there is no single market center as in the model of agricultural land use, there are points of maximum accessibility.  Recall how transport networks often have a point or set of points that are more accessible to all other points — especially if the network is radial, or hub-and-spoke.  Many urban highways, railways, and subways are essentially radial, with the center of the city being the point of maximum accessibility.

To the extent that the center is the point of maximum accessibility, it the point where transport costs are lowest.  So we can suggest that people will pay higher economic rent to locate nearer the city center, where transport costs are lowest to the combination of all other points.

Ri = D (r - c) - Dtdic

where
Ri = maximum rent or price that a particular use can pay for urban land at a particular point i, in dollars/acre
D = land-use density, in rentable sq.ft./acre (varies across types of activity and according to the zoning regulation in force)
r = revenues generated per sq.ft. of the activity (varies across types of activity)
c = costs of generating that revenue, in dollars/sq.ft. (varies across types of activity)
t = transport cost, in dollars/sq.ft.-mile:  think of this as the people who work, live, school, or shop there per sq.ft. of
         space, times the transit cost per person-mile = people/sq.ft. X $/person-mile = $/sq.ft.-mile;  this varies
            according to the "person-intensity" of the activity and the opportunity cost of those people's transport time.
dic = distance from the point in question to the point of maximum accessibility, in miles.

What is this equation saying?
(r - c) is the profit to be made per sq.ft. of rented space:  higher for high-volume department stores and for exclusive office space for corporate headquarters, lower for inexpensive housing or land-hungry manufacturing.
D (r - c) is the profit to be made per acre of land:  this gets pretty high even for inexpensive housing, if the density is great enough.
Dtdic is the cost to transport the people (and goods) that have to get to and from the site every day:  the denser the land use and the more people who use it per square foot of space, the more costly it is to be far from the point of maximum accessibility to everyone’s home and workplace.

The equation is saying that the portion of the economic return from an urban activity which can be attributed to the location of the activity equals the difference between (a) the profit to be made per acre of land, before transport costs and (b) the costs associated with moving goods and people to and from the location.

We can relate this equation to our linear rent gradients in the form Y = a - bXD (r - c) is the y-intercept (the rent at the point of maximum accessibility) and Dt is the slope.

If we assume that different urban land uses have different densities, we can understand a pattern of concentric zones around the point or points of maximum accessibility.  Hanink's Figure 2.9 and Stutz & deSouza's Figures 6.5 and 6.6 show this when there is one point of maximum accessibility;  we can also show a more complicated pattern when there are several points of great accessibility, as where a circumferential highway (the Beltway around Washington, D.C., or Route 128 and Route 495 around Boston) intersects the radial highways leading into the center of town.

Note that this framework has the same assumptions (follow this link)  and is built in the same general way (follow this link) as the agricultural land use model.  This general approach, its strengths (simplicity), and its weaknesses (its strong assumptions) should become very familiar to you by the end of this course.
 


COMPLICATIONS  AND  TRANSITIONS

The resultant urban land uses are complicated by the dynamic nature of urban development:  as the city grows, each ring gets larger.

[illustrate the rings expanding, as the prices at the center rise with greater overall population]

 But there are already buildings and infrastructure from the earlier land uses.  So we get “zones of transition,” where former warehouses or manufacturing lofts are used for a mix of functions, until the land becomes so valuable that they are demolished and the land used for higher-density office or residential functions.

The pattern is also disturbed by linear or radial infrastructure that is in place as a city grows:  major rail lines that remain industrial over time, or landscaped parkland that is desired by the most expensive housing.  This leads to a sector pattern of urban land uses.

Note how we just “played with” this model:  we asked what would happen over time if the total size of the city increased.  The answer, in this simple model, is that the rents rise throughout the area:  the zones increase in size, and the spatial margin of the city expands.  To use the algebraic terms, r increases, which drives up the y-intercept of each land-use rent gradient, without affecting the slopes of the gradients.

We can play in another way:  what happens if transport costs decrease, uniformly, over time?  Each of the sloping lines would flatten:  rents would lower throughout the city, and the spatial extent would increase.  (See Stutz & deSouza Figure 6.15).  To use the algebraic terms, t would decrease, which reduces the slope of each land-use gradient, while the y-intercepts remain the same.  The shift to car and truck travel and massive investment in highways have reduced the cost of transportation for individuals in the U.S. since World War Two.

If gasoline prices were to rise substantially (say, by a factor of three), the sloped lines would get steeper, the zones and the spatial extent of the city would get smaller, rents would increase in more accessible locations, and densities would increase.  To use the algebraic terms, t would increase, which increases the slope of each land-use gradient, while the y-intercepts remain the same.

What happens if the dominant density of a given land use changes?  During the middle of the 20th century, manufacturing technology changed manufacturing from a fairly dense land use to a fairly land-hungry land use.  To use the algebraic terms, D has fallen for this particular land use, which decreases the y-intercept and the slope for this land use.  Correspondingly, manufacturing has shifted from inner to outer rings of most metropolitan areas.


POLITICAL  REALITIES

Land-use zoning
The actual patterns of land use in a North American city (except Houston) reflect the decisions of local governments regarding land-use zoning.  These decisions generally follow the market, however, because

Hanink, pp. 132-135, presents a description and graphical depiction of urban land-use zoning.  Be familiar with the nature and effects of zoning.

Balkanization of the metropolis
Most large metropolitan areas are actually divided into many separate municipalities, each one collecting its own property taxes and supporting its own schools, fire departments, etc.  As the metropolitan area expands its spatial extent, a smaller and smaller proportion of it is within the central city.  The central city then has to support big-city functions (major library, large police force for all the tourists and in-commuting workers, extra educational expenses for populations that need additional educational assistance) with a shrinking proportion of the region’s tax base:  taxes per household increase, which accelerates the process of suburbanization.

Informal housing
Most housing in U.S. metropolitan areas is built professionally and according to building codes.  In Latin America, however, poor households may build housing themselves on land that they don’t formally own or rent.  These informal housing settlements are generally on the edge of town — so the pattern of housing is the opposite of most North American cities, where most wealthy people live in land-use-controlled suburbs and most poor, urban residents live in the central city.


copyright James W. Harrington, Jr.
revised 1 April 2000