University
of Washington
Geography
349 (Professor
Harrington)
Who’s Competing With
Whom?...
And With What Consequences for Whom?
Contents:
Note that these
online notes refer you to the Dicken reading, to another
set of on-line notes, and optionally to reading in the Daniels
&
Radebaugh text.
DEFINING COMPETITIVENESS
opportunity cost (of an
activity):
the value of the most productive activity that could be undertaken with
the resources used in that activity.
-
The opportunity cost of your time in class is
the
value of the best alternative use of those two hours.
-
One measure of the opportunity cost of a
Federal
subsidy to software producers is the interest expense of additional
Federal
debt (or the GDP reduction due to additional Federal taxes).
comparative advantage (of person or place
1): the economic production that can be undertaken with the
lowest
opportunity cost, which is to say the most productive activity that can
be undertaken in setting 1 using resources X and Y
-
The comparative advantage of a worker is the
production
or the activity in which the worker (equipped with the worker's
specific
blend of skills, experiences, and tools) can produce the highest value
of product in a given period of time.
-
The comparative advantage of a region;
of a
country:
In a 2X2 world (2 countries, 2 products), we might set up a table such
as this:
Value of inputs required to produce 1 unit of:
COUNTRY |
BEER |
WINE |
California |
CB |
CW |
Alaska |
AB |
AW |
If CB/CW > AB/AW, then the comparative advantage of California is
wine
and of Alaska is beer.
revealed comparative advantage: the
sectors in which the national share of world export markets is greater
than the overall national share of overall world exports:
(en,i/ew,i)
> (en/ew) where ei are
exports from country n in industry i, en
is total national exports, and ew is total world
exports.
In what sectors would you expect the US to
have RCA? (Well, what are the US's abundant or especially
productive
factors? Agricultural land, certain minerals, skilled labor,
managerial
labor, financial capital).
In what sectors does the US have RCA?
- In 1967: aircraft mfg; office
equipment;
precision instruments; agric. equipment; construction
equipment;
printed matter; cosmetics; tobacco products; animal
food;
(grain products)
- In 1981, all the above except the ones
in parentheses
What are the
problems with using this as a proxy for RCA?
1) Trade barriers may prevent a country from exporting products
in which it has a comparative advantage.
2) Factor prices may not reflect factor endowments, because of minimum
wages, government subsidies, etc.
3) Domestic demand for a product in which a country has comparative
advantage may be so high that all production is consumed internally.
4) Production of a major export may not be sustainable.
competitive advantage (of an enterprise):
the ability to produce consistently at lower cost, higher quality, or
greater
customization than the enterprise's competitors, because of some
proprietary
elements of the enterprise (location, technology, personnel, supplier
relationships,
etc.);
-
note that the greatest goal of a business is
to control
a resource on which it can earn an economic rent that exceeds the
normal
profit rate: a proprietary technology, a valuable trademark, a
unique
natural resource...
-
the more proprietary the source of advantage,
the
more secure the advantage; the most proprietary characteristics
of
an enterprise is the way in which it combines the elements of market
identification,
product development, procurement, production, and distribution:
what
Porter calls the "value chain"
competitive advantage (of a country or region):
the set of activities in which enterprises (companies;
state-owned
enterprises) based in the country tend toward international competitive
advantage;
-
thus, the concept relies both on the microeconomic
concerns of enterprise competitive advantage and the macroeconomic
concerns of comparative advantage;
-
the concept recognizes that:
-
most international trade and
competition is
between companies, not countries, but
-
there are country-specific
characteristics
that affect the likelihood of a company's success internationally, and
-
these characteristics have varying
relevance
for different activities (industries).
We can define international
competitiveness as in the 1985 President's Commission on Industrial
Competitiveness :
the degree to which a nation can,
(1) under free and fair market conditions, produce goods and services
(2)
that meet the test of international markets (3) while simultaneously
maintaining
or expanding the real income of its citizens.
Note that the fundamental mechanisms for
balancing
trade flows, involving the eventual depreciation of the currency of a
country
with a large (as a proportion of GDP), persistent trade deficit, may
increase
exports but don't increase real incomes. (See (optionally)
Harrington's
notes about social
policy relevant to maintaining international competitiveness).
In Pop Internationalism [quoted in the
Dicken reading], Krugman argues that for a country with relatively
little
international trade, the conditions above are the same as increasing
internal
total-factor productivity, period.
Competitiveness can be measured at the
national
scale or at the scale of individual industries.
-
National measures: trade
balances;
world export shares; rates of productivity growth; growth
in
real wages; low price elasticity of imports (implying preferences
for domestic products)
-
Note our caveat that a trade deficit can be
a sign
of strength (international desire to purchase assets in that
country;
net inward investment in future production) and a trade surplus can be
a sign of weakness (net capital outflow to pay international debt —
public
and private — because international markets are unwilling to continue
lending).
Remember the fundamental relationship between trade balances and
international
capital flows, which we can express with the identity S - I = X
-
M (the difference between the savings produced in an economy
and
the investment undertaken in that economy equals the difference between
exports from and imports to that economy; this is the same
as saying that a trade surplus is equalled by net capital
outflow).
-
Sectoral measures: change in
national
share of global production; change in employment (esp. of
production
workers); corporate revenues and profits; relative
frequency
of "industrial crises" (bankruptcies or other financial disruptions
that
potentially disrupt production and employment)
-
Note the potential for creative accounting
of multinational-corporation
revenues and profits from international trade, rendering this indicator
unreliable.
What are the sources of
competitiveness?
For some alternative approaches to this question, see Harrington's
notes
on the sources of competitiveness.
DYNAMIC
COMPARATIVE
ADVANTAGE
Temporal shifts in national comparative advantage
based on shifts in relative factor prices and development of new or
improved
factors.
-
Relative wages of unskilled and skill labor
may shift
as a result of international trade.
-
Supply of skilled and technical labor may
increase
with development and investment.
-
Availability of physical infrastructure may
increase
with development and investment, changing internal factor costs (e.gf.,
making certain natural resources more economically available for
industrial
development or trade).
DYNAMIC
COMPETITIVE
ADVANTAGE: changes in Porter's "diamond"
(see Dicken pp. 82-86 and (optionally) Daniels
& Radebaugh, pp. 218-220 for an introduction to Porter's
diamond.
Porter’s Competitive Advantage of
Nations,
Chapter 10: The Competitive Development of National Economies
Moves from industry scale to national
scale.
Implicitly defines economic development (p.544)
as
"achieving higher-order competitive
advantages
[e.g., from natural resource availability to infrastructure,
organizational
capabilities, labor-force characteristics, sophisticated supporting and
market industries, etc.] in existing industries and developing the
capability
to compete successfully in new, high-productivity segments and
industries."
Defines stages of competitive
development
according to the sources of competitive advantage in the nation's
internationally
competitive sectors:
FACTOR DRIVEN,
in which basic factor conditions (incl. basic labor) are the source of
advantage
- note that import substitution is not
a way to develop out of this stage; the quality of the basic
factors
can't be improved by protecting them from external competition
Policy: improve basic factors
INVESTMENT DRIVEN,
in which more advanced factors are added to basic factors, along with
intense
domestic rivalry, and the beginnings of a demanding domestic market
(esp.
for particular, generally low-end segments of the industries' markets).
- scale is important; this stage is
achieved
via industries that have substantial scale economies, that retain a
large
L component, and in which international competition is via price/ cost.
- investment is by companies, workers,
families, and governments (incl., perhaps, the allocation of K to
sectors)
Can "infant industry" protection improve
competitive
advantage in this stage? (Note the political difficulties).
Can export promotion (including, if
necessary,
opening internal markets) improve competitive advantage
INNOVATION DRIVEN,
in which all elements of the diamond are in operation;
interestingly,
however, it is selective factor disadvantages rather than advantages
that
motivate some innovation
- vertical deepening of advantage as
capabilities
and demands grow among suppliers and users of key industries
("technological
multipliers")
- government role? stimulate
advanced-factor
creation, preserving rivalry
Relate this to “new trade theory” and to
Krugman’s
presentation of technology-based trade theory (Ch. 6), with two key
considerations:
1) external economies of technological
development,
that benefit firms and the overall economy beyond the innovative firm,
via processes of labor and information diffusion
2) internal economies of scale in the
innovative
firm’s use of technology
To the extent that these processes operate at
national
or sub-national scales, they provide nationally reinforcing comparative
and competitive advantages.
Can competitive advantage in this stage be
extended through strategic industrial policy?
WEALTH DRIVEN,
in which a nation and its component industries and factors essentially
spend past investments in growth, productivity, and innovation
- chronic under-investment in industry
(and in industry factors)
- wealth can drive certain elements of
an economy, such as the industries that cater to wealth, expensive
tastes,
or wealth management; industries where certain advantages are
especially
durable because of highly specialized infrastructure, factors, or
demand
(e.g., national defense); or industries that have faced little
technological
change since the nation achieved substantial competitive advantage
Can such a economy sustain itself in the
long
term?
Note the differences between this model and the
more
traditional models of economic development (e.g., "dynamic comparative
advantage," above) that rely on the creation and upgrading of factors,
and on constant increases in L productivity that allows wages to
increase
and thereby motivate even greater increases in L productivity. In
Porter's model, factors, even advanced factors, are not sufficient.
For a further explication of the role of
government
in these alternative frameworks of competitiveness, see Harrington's
notes
on the role of government.
copyright James W.
Harrington,
Jr.
revised 14 October 2008