University
of
Washington
Geography
349
Labor
Impacts of Trade
Types of Economic Influences of Trade
on Labor
1. Increased trade
should increase
returns to relatively abundant
factors, whose output finds greater
demand (because products that rely heavily on
those abundant factors are exported). This would include
highly skilled labor in most
advanced economies, and
relatively unskilled labor in less advanced
economies. In the
former countries, this would
exacerbate wage differentials;
in the
latter, it might mitigate wage differentials.
2.
Factor
price equalization.
This should be limited by international
differences in the productivity of a
unit of (in this case), labor –
differences stemming from direct capital used
in production, capital
infrastructure, human capital such as
literacy, education, and basic
health/strength, and organization/management. All of these
differences increase the productivity
of labor, and to the
extent that Q/L (output per unit of labor) is
higher in wealthier countries, factor price
equalization would end when w1/w2
= Q1/L1 /
Q2/L2 (when the relative wages
of the two trading partners equals the
relative labor productivity of the two
countries).
3.
FDI
should increase labor
productivity, especially in
less-wealthy countries, because of differences
in the “imported”
technology and
capital – and maybe management (except to the
extent that good HR mgmt
is a
localized practice).
By
noting
the sequence of events in Canada,
Larose [2000]
suggested that
Canada’s trade surplus with the US was
· not a
result of NAFTA, and
· not a
result of increased Canadian productivity,
but was
· a
result of decline in the Canadian dollar
(caused
by loosened monetary policy), which had the
effect of reducing the
returns to
Canadian factors [and reducing the gains
from trade].
Labor
standards
Some
propose worldwide
minimum wages that approximate those in
wealthy countries
– which eliminates export-oriented employment
in poorer countries,
whose
workers are at a productivity disadvantage.
However,
different labor
and
environmental standards can affect labor
productivity. Lower
standards increase short-term
productivity, such as not paying workers, or
long work hours without
breaks, or
lack of a minimum working age, …
Should
we have global labor standards outside of
wages and benefits (“core
standards” as opposed to “cash
standards”
in the phrasing of
Elliott 2004)?
Core
standards: “fundamental
principles
and rights at work” [Elliott 2004]
-
Freedom
of association and
the right
to collective bargaining
-
Abolition
of forced labor
-
Elimination
of child labor
-
Non-discrimination
in
employment
(generally focused on gender)
Elliott discusses
how each of these
might affect low-wage countries’ manifestation
of comparative advantage
– (1)
may increase wages; (2)
and (3) might reduce labor supply; and (4) might
increase labor supply (but
might increase wages)
Such standards are
currently outside of most trade
agreements
The labor chapter in the
Chile and Singapore FTAs and CAFTA
calls on parties to the agreement to enforce
their own laws but does
not
require that those laws be consistent with
international standards
[Elliott
2004:6].
Elliott presents some info
about how
different countries have dealt with these
matters – take a
look at the article.
Moving
toward international labor standards:
1. Through
national
adoption of ILO standards:
with what enforcement mechanisms?
2. Through
multilateral
agreements adopting labor standards, or
through
regional or bilateral agreements about or
adopting labor standards.
a. Insisting
that traded
items be
produced in compliance with each country’s
standards
b. Insisting
that each
country’s
standards meet basic int’l standards?
c. With
what enforcement? the
same sorts of enforcement mechanisms
generated for trade disputes?
3. Through
markets
–
a. consumer
action, country
by country
b. Through
markets
-- consumer action, company by company: requires
the international transmittal of a
great deal of information (typically via
certification)
4. Through
international
labor
coordination and action:
labor does not
have to be a passive victim (see below).
5.
Through labor
migration to
countries
with better wages and working conditions.
“NAFTA has brought the
issue of
continental labor cooperation to the fore of
labor union strategy,… as
a
necessary and concrete tactic in the era of
the regionalized production
system”
[MacDonald 2003: 173].
The NAALC (North American
Agreement on
Labor Cooperation)
- “requires
member countries
to comply
with and effectively enforce their
respective
labor laws [relating] to 11 core
principles” [MacDonald
2003:
180].
- If
a country is found to
be
non-compliant with its own laws, other
countries can complain and
perhaps even
levy countervailing duties on traded goods
originating in the offending
country.
- But
is this a “’resource
intensive
dead end”’ [181]?
International
labor cooperation: "Workers
of the world unite" -- but how?
NAFTA’s “resultant job and
wage
losses and further erosion of bargaining power
have convinced many
Canadian and
American unionists of the need to cooperate
with Mexican unions to
raise wages
and standards” [185].
·
Unions can attempt
to
organize workers across the countries in which
a particular company (e.g., General Motors)
operates.
·
Unions can attempt
to
organize workers in the same sector (e.g., the
automobile sector) in each country.
·
Unions
can share information about employers’ tactics
and operations in different countries.
·
Unions can
bring worker pressure in one country to bear
on its employer, based
on the
employer’s actions in another country.
Reasons for
international labor cooperation:
·
By
reducing the importance of work conditions as
a basis for corporate
location
decisions, other factors (such as
infrastructure, logistics of moving
inputs or
products, tax and investment regulation) come
to the fore – not the
factors
that influence households’ ability to survive.
“’the best way to defend
jobs in the United States is to work
together to elevate the level of salaries and
workplace and
environmental
conditions in Mexico’” [185].
·
Allowing
labor to be as international as capital.
Barriers to
international labor cooperation [ask]:
·
Sense
that the issues are separate
·
Sense
that the major goal is to maintain current,
national jobs and wages, by
focusing efforts nationally and opposing
imports (which employ workers
elsewhere)
·
Linguistic
and cultural barriers
·
Institutional
structures – who elects the union leadership?
Note MacDonald’s
description [2003: 188] of the Coalition for
Justice in the Maquiladoras, under the
auspices of the AFL-CIO, but
with
somewhat independent authority to act on
behalf of maquiladora workers
and communities.
·
Institutional
structures: unions
may have very
different constituencies in different
countries (the state; highly
skilled workers; unskilled
workers…]
Economist
article
focuses on labor migration
·
Bottom
line: labor
resources are mobile, but do
often take on wage/cost characteristics
approximating those of the
destination
country – unless the migration flow is so
large as to change the
overall factor
mix of the destination country.
·
Influences
on migration:
o Motivation: levels of un- and
under-employment; focused
political persecution
o Legal
restrictions
(usually by destination countries); and
their enforcement
o Degree
of
difficulty (transport costs, information,
set-up)
·
Impacts
of migration:
o Increased
supply
of labor (note that Y
= λ KαLβ
)-- national output is a function of
technology, capital, and labor.
o (Potentially,
reduced
wages, if the demand for the relevant types of
labor does not
increase)
§ inflow
of refugees to
Miami from the
Cuban port of Mariel in 1980. Within the space
of a few months, 125,000
people
had arrived, increasing Miami’s labour force
by 7%. Yet the study
concluded
that wages and employment among the city’s
natives, including the
unskilled,
were virtually unaffected.
§ In
his 1997 book Trade and Income
Distribution, William Cline reviews the
literature
on globalisation and wages. In general, Mr
Cline’s estimates tend to
the
pessimistic end of the range. Nonetheless he
finds that of all the
forces
acting to lower unskilled wages relative to
skilled, immigration is the
weakest. According to his estimates, immigration
would by itself account for a fall of two
percentage points in the
ratio of
unskilled to skilled wages in America
between 1973 and 1993.
Technological
change, acting to reduce the demand for
unskilled labour, and a
category called
“unidentified factors” pushing the same way
would each account for a
much
greater fall of nearly 30 percentage points.
o (Potentially),
increased
supply of skills
o Increased
household
demand (note that Y =
C + I + G + X
–M)
References:
The
Economist. Workers of the
world.
Kimberly
Ann
Elliott
(2004). Labor
Standards, Development, and CAFTA. Institute
for International Economics Policy
Brief 04-2.
Gèrald
Larose
(2000). Globalization
and the
social dimension. Pp.
159-165 in Free Trade: Risks and
Rewards, ed. by L.
Ian MacDonald. Montreal:
McGill-Queen’s
University Press.
Ian
Thomas
MacDonald (2003). NAFTA
and the
emergence of continental labor cooperation. The
American Review of Canadian
Studies (Summer): 173-196.
copyright James W.
Harrington
revised 13
February 2014
|