Spatial interaction is motivated by a deficit
(or demand) in one place and a surplus (or supply) in another, right?
Well, what better example of supply than all the "stuff" in a retail store?
We can use our simple model of spatial interaction to model the amount
of demand around a retail outlet, on the assumption that people:
(a) have to pay the costs (in money and time) to get to and from a retail
outlet, and (b) want to minimize those costs, so long as they can buy what
they need. We can even model the shape of the market area
around an outlet, if we know the locations of competing outlets.
Then, we can do things like tailor our marketing plan to characteristics
and needs of people in the market area -- or figure out where to locate
a new retail outlet to be in the midst of the kind of market area we
think will best suit the kinds of things we're selling!
MARKET POTENTIAL (see the
Hanink text, page 245-246)
Recall our model for the interaction
between
two places, i and j:
Well, if we’re concerned with the total flow to j from all points i, we would create a formula like
Ij = k (sum Pi dij-a) Pj
which is the sum of all the interactions between all i’s and a particular j.
If we are establishing a retail store or shopping center at j, and we want to estimate how many shoppers will use it, we care about this kind of total flow from all i’s to j. We would expect to get more shoppers from nearby places, and from places with larger populations. These “places” would be sub-areas of a region — census tracts, for example.
In the equation above, since Pj is a constant, we can multiply it by k, the other constant, to yield a new constant Mj = kPj, resulting in a simpler formula
Ij = Mj (sumPi dij-a)
which is the same as
Ij = Mj (sum Pi / dija)
This is a measure of the potential
interaction between point j and all the surrounding points
i.
If we think of j as a retail store or a shopping center,
and each i as a zone nearby (each zone has a particular population
and a particular distance from j), then Ij
is a measure of the potential number of shoppers destined to j.
This is sometimes called the
market potential of j.
You can see that Ij is high for places j that are close to heavily
populated zones, and low for places j that are far from heavily populated
zones. While this is intuitive, this measure gives you a systematic
way to compare two locations that seem quite similar to one another
(downtown Everett versus downtown Tacoma).
See Figure 6.16 in the S&deS text, which implicitly uses this
formula (though in that simple example, k = 1 and a = 1).
Now, if we’re talking about the potential for retail sales at a point j, there are better variables than the population of surrounding zones or tracts. We need some measure of purchasing power, such as total personal income in each zone i.Even better would be a measure of general purchasing power or personal income, multiplied by the proportion of that income that is spent on the kinds of things our store would be selling.
This is precisely what you’ll do in the second assignment. You’ll be estimating the amount of retail sales you’d get in a retail store at a particular location j, by allowing the computer to compute the sales that the store should get from customers in each of several zones i. You’ll tell the computer the total household income in each zone, and the proportion of total income spent on groceries. The computer will compute the distance from each i to j, and the consequent level of sales (S) expected from all the zones in the market area of the store.
Sj = k X sum (Ci / dija)
where Ci = food or drug or furniture expenditures
in i = (household income in i) (proportion of
income spent on food or drugs or furniture). To make this clearer,
this is the parameter k multiplied by: each zone's food (etc.)
purchases divided by the distance of that zone from location j,
summed across all the zones i.
Here's a link to a well-written example of a similar case, provided by a commercial GIS firm. |
COMPETING MARKET CENTERS
A further elaboration is to recognize that
where
BC
= "breaking point" between
the primary market areas of centers A and C, expressed as distance from
C
dAC
= distance between centers
A and C
PA
= population of city A or
square footage of shopping center A
PC =
population
of city C or square footage of shopping
center C
This results from "Reilly's law of retail gravitation," which suggests that R, the retail attractiveness of a central place (or shopping center) j to a potential customer at i increases proportionately with the population P (or size in square feet) of j, and increases inversely with the square of the distance ij:
Rj = k Pj / Dij2
Note that whether we're using population or square
footage, the implication is that the greater possibility of finding more
of the goods/services needed, with only one trip, is a powerful attraction
of a customer to a particular place.